Total Pageviews

Friday, April 24, 2009

Why Americans pay more for health care

The United States spends more on health care than comparable countries do and more than its wealth would suggest. Here’s how—and why.
DECEMBER 2008 • Diana M. Farrell, Eric S. Jensen, and Bob Kocher
The health care debate in the United States excites great passion. Issues such as how to make care available, to structure insurance, and to rein in spending by the government, corporations, and individuals frequently take center stage. Often missing, though, are basic economic facts. New research from the McKinsey Global Institute (MGI) and McKinsey’s health care practice sheds light on a critical piece of the puzzle: the cost of care.
Our research indicates that the United States spends $650 billion more on health care than might be expected given the country’s wealth and the experience of comparable members of the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). The research also pinpoints where that extra spending goes. Roughly two-thirds of it pays for outpatient care, including visits to physicians, same-day hospital treatment, and emergency-room care. The next-largest contributors to the extra spending are drugs and administration and insurance.
It’s not clear whether the United States gets $650 billion worth of extra value. Parts of the US health care system, such as its best hospitals, are clearly world class. Cutting-edge drugs and treatments are available earlier there, and waiting times to see physicians tend to be lower. Yet the country lags behind other OECD members on a number of outcome measures, including life expectancy and infant mortality. Furthermore, access to health care is unequal: more than 45 million Americans lack insurance.
The challenge for health care reformers is to retain the current system’s strengths while addressing its deficiencies and curbing costs. That won’t be easy. Our research on the system’s costs and the incentives underlying them indicates that without the involvement of all major stakeholders (such as hospitals, payers, and doctors) reform is likely to prove elusive. The research also suggests that while there are many possible paths to reform, it is unlikely to succeed unless it deals comprehensively with health care demand, supply, and payments.
A $650 billion spending gap
Across the world, richer countries generally spend a disproportionate share of their income on health care. In the language of economics, it is a “superior good.” Just as wealthier people might spend a larger proportion of their income to buy bigger homes or homes in better neighborhoods, wealthier countries tend to spend more on health care.
Yet even accounting for this economic relationship, the United States still spends $650 billion more on health care than might be inferred from its wealth. MGI arrived at this figure by using data from 13 OECD countries to develop a metric called estimated spending according to wealth (ESAW), which adjusts health care expenditures according to per capita GDP. No other developed country’s spending above the ESAW level approaches that of the United States
Is it paying so much more because its people are less healthy than those of other countries? Our research indicates that the answer is no. While lifestyle-induced diseases, such as obesity, are on the rise in the United States, the most common diseases are, on average, slightly less prevalent there than in peer OECD members. The factors contributing to the lower disease rates include the relatively younger (and therefore less disease-prone) population of the United States, as well as the low prevalence of smoking-related problems. Factoring in the average cost of treatment for each disease, we still find that the relative health of the US population does not account for the higher cost of health care.
Analyzing the problem
MGI broke down health care costs into their components to identify the sources of this higher-than-expected spending. Outpatient care is by far the largest and fastest-growing part of it, accounting for $436 billion, or two-thirds of the $650 billion figure. The cost of drugs and the cost of health care administration and insurance (all nonmedical costs incurred by health care payers) account for an additional $98 billion and $91 billion, respectively, in extra spending. By contrast, US expenditures on long-term and home care, as well as on durable medical equipment (such as eyeglasses, wheelchairs, and hearing aids), is actually less than would be expected given the country’s wealth.
Outpatient care
The high and fast-growing cost of outpatient care reflects a structural shift in the United States away from inpatient settings, such as overnight hospital stays. Today, the US system delivers 65 percent of all care in outpatient contexts, up from 43 percent in 1980, and well above the OECD average of 52 percent. In theory, this shift should help to save money, since fixed costs in outpatient settings tend to be lower than the cost of overnight hospital stays. In reality, however, the shift to outpatient care has added to—not taken away from—total system costs because of the higher utilization of outpatient care in the United States.
We evaluated the economic impact of this structural shift by analyzing US inpatient care and comparing it with the practices of other OECD health systems. We estimate that the United States saves $100 billion to $120 billion a year on inpatient care thanks to shorter hospital stays and fewer hospital admissions. If we attribute these savings to the US health system’s ability to provide care in outpatient settings, that would reduce above-ESAW outpatient expenditures—but only to $326 billion. This enormous figure still represents half of the US health care system’s $650 billion in extra costs.
The two largest and fastest-growing categories of outpatient spending are same-day hospital care and visits to physicians’ offices. From 2003 to 2006, the cost of these two categories increased by 9.3 and 7.9 percent a year, respectively. Growth in the number of visits played only a modest role in explaining the increase in costs—the number of same-day hospital visits rose by 2.1 percent annually, and the number of visits to physicians’ offices remained relatively flat during this period.
Far more important was a surge in the average cost per visit resulting from factors such as the additional care delivered during visits, a shift toward more expensive procedures (for example, diagnostic ones such as CT and MRI scans), and absolute price increases for equivalent procedures.1 In all likelihood, costs have also gone up because over the past decade there has been a marked shift in the delivery of care, from general practitioners to specialists.
Behind those proximate causes, several forces contribute to the rising cost of outpatient care across the entire range of settings, not just same-day hospital stays and visits to physicians’ offices. For starters, outpatient care is highly profitable—US hospitals earn a significant percentage of their profits from elective same-day care—which prompts investments in the facilities and people supporting it. These investments can be recouped only by offering more (and more expensive) services. The significant degree of discretion that physicians have over the course and extent of outpatient treatment also probably plays a role, as does the fee-for-service reimbursement system, which creates financial incentives to provide more outpatient care.
Finally, there is no effective check on it. On average, the out-of-pocket expense of patients represents only 15 percent of the total cost, so they are relatively insensitive to it and apt to follow the advice of their physicians. Other countries also have low out-of-pocket expenses but use supply-oriented controls to compensate for the lack of demand-side value consciousness.
Pharmaceuticals
After outpatient care, the category with the highest above-ESAW expenditures, at $98 billion, is prescription drugs—not because Americans are buying more of them but rather because they cost 50 percent more than equivalent products in other OECD countries.2 The United States also uses a more expensive mix of drugs; the price of a statistically average pill is 118 percent higher than that of its OECD equivalents. One reason is probably that new drugs, which tend to carry a price premium, are widely prescribed one to two years earlier in the United States than in Europe.
Several frequent explanations for higher US drug prices deserve examination. One is the wealth of the United States, which enables it to spend more on economically superior goods, such as drugs. Another is that high US prices subsidize research and development for the rest of the world. Marketing and sales spending by companies is higher in the United States than in other OECD countries (which generally restrict direct-to-physician or consumer advertising), and that also could play a role.
But none of these factors, by itself, can explain the gap between the price of drugs in the United States and the rest of the OECD. When we adjust for US wealth, we find that the country’s branded-drug prices should carry a premium of some 30 percent, not 77 percent for branded small-molecule drugs. Similarly, if global pharma R&D spending—$40 billion to $50 billion in 2006—were financed entirely through higher branded-drug prices, the US price premium over similar countries would be 23 to 28 percent. Finally, in 2006 the sales and marketing expenditures of US pharma companies came to $30 billion to $40 billion, only 17 to 23 percent of current US prices.
Health administration and insurance
The third-largest source of above-ESAW spending is health administration and insurance, at $91 billion. In this category, the United States spent $486 per capita in 2006—twice the outlay of the next-highest spender, France, with $248, and nearly five times the average of $103 across peer OECD countries.
Of the $91 billion in above-expected spending, $63 billion is attributable to private payers. Profits and taxes—a negligible expense in OECD countries with single-payer systems—account for nearly half of this total. The cost of public administration for Medicare, Medicaid, and other government programs accounts for the remaining $28 billion in US above-ESAW spending.
These higher costs largely reflect the diversity and number of payers as well as the multistate regulation of the US health care system. Its structure creates additional costs and inefficiencies: redundant marketing, underwriting, claims processing, and management overhead. In other OECD countries, with less-fragmented payment systems, these costs are much lower. Interestingly, we find that given the structure of the US system, its administrative costs are actually $19 billion less than expected, suggesting that payers have had some success in restraining costs.
Of course, the US multipayer system could create value to the extent that it develops effective programs to promote health and prevent disease, competes to drive down prices, innovates to improve customer service or benefits, or offers patients greater choice. But do the virtues of the US system outweigh its inefficiencies, and can these inefficiencies be reduced within its current structure?
A framework for reform
The United States can take no single path to address the level and growth of every one of its health care costs. Any reform effort should involve all of the system’s stakeholders, for the inclusion of hospitals, payers, and doctors in the reform effort will increase the odds of arriving at a plan for change that each party will truly embrace. Furthermore, each party can play a distinct role in addressing the full spectrum of issues that must be part of any major system overhaul. For each of these areas, there are several possibilities for reform—such as raising public awareness, creating appropriate incentives, mandating desired behavior, and taking direct action.
For health care reform to generate lasting improvements in cost, quality, access, and equity, it must effectively address supply, demand, and payment.3 A number of our McKinsey colleagues recently completed an effort to determine what would be required to change trends in health care costs fundamentally. Here, we briefly lay out the principal issues for consideration by all health care reformers.
Demand
The general health of the US population is a significant issue. Although disease is no more prevalent in the United States than in peer OECD countries, the health of its population is falling, and this decline contributes to the growth in medical costs. In fact, our analysis suggests that in the two-year period from 2003 to 2005, the decline raised them by $20 billion to $40 billion. Reformers should therefore focus on the preventative efforts that present the largest opportunity to improve overall health and thereby save money.
Equally important is the lack of any real value consciousness. In the United States, the “average” consumer of health care pays for only 12 percent of its total cost directly out of pocket (down from 47 percent in 1960), as well as for 25 percent of health care insurance premiums, a share that has stayed relatively constant for the last decade. Well-insured patients who bear little, if any, of the cost of their treatment have no incentive to be value-conscious health care consumers.
Moreover, even if they wanted to be value conscious, they don’t know enough. Despite recent efforts to expand consumer access to information on health care, its cost and quality remain opaque—arguably more so than in any other consumer industry. Consumers also know vastly less than providers do and therefore understandably rely on the advice and guidance of physicians. If Americans are to become more value-conscious consumers of health care, reformers must therefore determine how to create an appropriate level of price sensitivity and to give patients the right information, decision tools, and incentives.
Supply
In many industries, such as consumer electronics, innovation tends to drive down prices. The opposite is true in health care, where lower prices don’t necessarily boost sales and may even create the perception of low quality. Instead, innovation tends to focus on the development of increasingly more expensive products and techniques. High-priced technologies, from imaging to surgical equipment, also mean higher reimbursements for providers, who therefore demand cutting-edge products. So what emerges is a constant cycle of cost inflation along the entire health care value chain—from manufacturers of health products to equipment manufacturers to physicians to hospitals to payers and, ultimately, to employers and patients. At each step, the stakeholders absorb part of the cost increase and attempt to pass an even larger one onto the next stakeholder. Reformers must determine how to address this cost inflation cycle while retaining the beneficial aspects of innovation.
Intermediation
Medicare and many commercial payers base their reimbursements for inpatient care on episodes or diagnosis-related groups (DRGs). This forces providers to bear part of the risk of treating a patient and largely creates incentives to use resources efficiently. But fee-for-service reimbursement, the predominant method in outpatient treatment, does not have that effect and actually gives providers strong financial incentives to provide more (and more costly) care, not more value. Fear of malpractice suits boosts care volumes too. Our research indicates that the direct costs of malpractice are limited—about $30 billion in 2006—but the risk of litigation creates an incentive to err on the side of caution. Reformers therefore need to develop more effective financing and payment approaches ensuring that care providers have the right incentives to give patients an appropriate type and amount of care.
Medicare’s role in influencing coverage and pricing dynamics also bears investigation. Private payers use this public program as a critical benchmark, more often than not following its lead, when they make decisions about which new procedures and technologies to reimburse. Because Medicare essentially uses a cost-plus formula to set reimbursement rates, it puts care providers under less pressure to reduce expenses than it could with another reimbursement mechanism. What’s more, trends in the reimbursement rates of commercial payers are strongly correlated—but inversely—with Medicare pricing trends: private insurers grant providers higher increases when Medicare reimbursements grow more slowly. This suggests both that Medicare prices partly drive so-called market prices and that care providers have a significant amount of pricing power with private insurers. Reformers need to determine how public programs, such as Medicare and Medicaid, can lead the market toward rational change in reimbursement approaches and levels.
Reform won’t be easy. But armed with the facts about what the United States spends on different aspects of health care, how much above what might be expected that spending really is, and the underlying economic dynamics of the system, policy makers will have a better chance to curb the growth of costs.
About the Authors
Diana Farrell is director of the McKinsey Global Institute, and Eric Jensen is a consultant in McKinsey’s Washington, DC, office, where Bob Kocher is a principal.
Notes
1CT (computerized tomography) and MRI (magnetic resonance imaging) scans are diagnostic tests that provide high-resolution pictures of the structure of any organ or part of the body requiring examination.
2Fifty percent represents the weighted average premium for branded drugs (77 percent), biologics (35 percent), and generics (–11 percent).
3 For more on a reform framework encompassing supply, demand, and payment for care, see Diana Farrell, Nicolaus P. Henke, and Paul D. Mango, “Universal principles for health care reform,” mckinseyquarterly.com, February 2007; and Jean P. Drouin, Viktor Hediger, and Nicolaus Henke, “Health care costs: A market-based view,” mckinseyquarterly.com, September 2008.

No comments:

A Flowchart for Choosing Your Religion

A Flowchart for Choosing Your Religion

Looking for a JOB - How to Be the Next Hire

Making You the Most Viable Next Hire
Being flexible, creative and adaptable in today’s economy is the cornerstone to survival. The job search is no different and, with unemployment rising, requires just as much vigilance. One way you can keep your options open and make yourself even more marketable is by considering Consulting in addition to your quest for full-time employment. Often perceived as an “either-or” scenario, Consulting offers you just as many benefits as it does your “would be” employer:

Track record of Fixing Problems?
Career wise, people typically fall into one of two categories: those who thrive on problem solving and the prospect of a new challenge –or- someone who is exceptionally good at steering the ship once it is on course. If the thought of fixing something that is broken appeals to you (versus has you thinking about reaching for the Tylenol), then Consulting might be an avenue to explore.

A More Flexible Interview
Quite often, what a company needs is someone to tackle a specific problem, not a new full-time employee. Identifying this in the interview and being able to present yourself as the solution to their problem (at a lower cost), can ultimately create a job tailor made for you and your skill set. No one can compete against that.

Dating Before Marriage
A consulting engagement can give you the opportunity to see if this company is a nice place to visit or a great place to live. The only thing worse than a prolonged job search, is ending up in a position that results in you being unemployed again in 6-12 months. Consulting lets you do more due diligence than you could ever accomplish in an interview.

“Consulting” on Your Resume
To many recruiters, seeing “consulting” as your current role without any clients/engagements is just a way to dress up being out of work. But, with a list of key accomplishments at those engagements, you show that you are in demand, have more control over your search and are broadening your experience. The latter is extremely important if you are looking to transition industries.

Change Agent
For companies looking to make some sort of change internally (and you should like this if you have a track record of fixing problems), consulting is a more preferred approach versus hiring a permanent employee. It is much easier to come in as a consultant, effect the course correction and then hand it off to the internal leadership.

Money
Besides the obvious benefit of having income during your search, it also gives you breathing room to be more objective in selecting your next job.

It’s Easier to Find a Job When You Already Have One
So much of what makes this true is that fact that when you are employed, you tend to be a bit more objective because you have a “bird in hand.” Consulting (in addition to easing that financial strain, which helps here) can provide the self-assurance that comes along with being employed, which can get whittled away while unemployed.

Presenting yourself as a viable consultant or full time employee isn’t mutually exclusive. Rather, they are simply two sides to the same coin. For the companies where you interview, this will only make you more viable and versatile in your eyes. For you, there is nothing to lose. The worst thing that happens here is you generate some income to inevitable financial strain of your job search. On the other hand, you might just find through this process that you discover your next career move.

Bağdat Caddesi

Gel de parmaklara hakim ol, yapma bir Caddebostan, Bağdat Caddesi nostaljisi şimdi!...diğer bir deyişle 'Karşı taraf' . Cok uzun seneler yazları gittiğim, son yıllarda ise her Türkiye'ye gittiğimde kaldığım Istanbul'un bir başka eşşiz köşesi.
1960'lı 70'li yıllarda köşkleriyle, bahçelerinden salkım salkım sarkan ortancalarıyla, billur gibi denizliyle, 'sayfiye' yeri olmasıyla meşhur Erenköy, Suadiye, Caddebostan.

Dükkanların az, ağaçların çok olduğu, bunca yıl geçmesine rağmen hala güzelliğini koruyan Bağdat Caddesi. On, onbir yaşımdan itibaren yazlarım geçti oralarda. Sokaklarda oynanırdı o zamanlar, öyle pek araba filan geçmezdi. Doyasıya bisiklete binilir, el birakarak gitmek büyük marifet sayılır Erenköy, Saskınbakkal, Göztepe bisikletle rahat rahat gidilir dönülürdü. Deniz için bazı sokakların denize vardıkları noktalarda bulunan kayıkhanelerden saatlik ücretle kayık kiralanır, kadın erkek kürek çekmeyi bilir, kayıktan denize girilirdi. Bazı gençler dalıp iskele ayaklarından midye toplar bazıları ise sığ kumda zıpkınla vatos avlarlardı. Sokaklardan dondurmacılar geçerdi o zamanlar. Simdiki gibi binbir çeşit ne gezer 'Dondurma, Kaymaaak' diye bağıran dondurmacının küçücük arabasında sadece kaymaklı ve limonlu dondurma olur, bazen ise çeşit olsun diye vişneli bulunurdu.

Caddebostan Plajı'nın yanı sıra bir de üyelikle girilebilen klüpler vardı. Marmara Yelken Klubü başta olmak üzere, Balıkadamlar, Caddebostan Yat Klübü ve İstanbul Yelken. Eğer bunlardan birine üyeyseniz veya üye bir arkadaşınız varsa bazı sporları yapma veya izleme olanağınız olur, voleybol, ping pong oynar, kıyıdan yelkenlilerin yarışlarını izlerdiniz. Denizin ortasında ise köfteciler vardı. Bunlardan aklımda kalanı ise mayomuzun kenarına sıkıştırdığımız parayla yüzdüğümüz, veya kayıkla yanaştığımız 'Fıştak'tı. Dönerken yüzülüyorsa demirlemiş kayıklara tutuna tutuna, dinlene dinlene yüzülürdü.

Akşamüstüne doğru herkesi bir 'piyasa' heyecanı alırdı. Saçlar yıkanır, bildiğımız ütüyle ütülenerek düzeltilir, ve (Bağdat) Cadde'ye binbir tur atmaya çıkılırdı. Bir aşağı, bir yukarı. Parkur ise genellikle Santral Durağı'ndan Saşkınbakkala kadardı. O zaman 'cafe' adeti bir elin parmaklarını geçmez, 'Borsa'da yer bulabilmek için hızlı davranmak gerekir, 'Divan' ise gençlere çok pahalı geldiğinden ancak hafif 'yaşı geçmiş'lerin duraklama mekanı olurdu. Hali varaba sahiakti oldukça yerinde olan birkaç genç ise bir aşağı bir yukarı arabayla giderek Mustang veya Corvette'leriyle gelene geçene hava atarlardı.

Geceleri ise açık hava sinemalarının keyfine doyulmazdı. Caddebostan'daki Ozan Sineması'nda genellikle Türk filmleri oynar, çıkınca biraz aşağıda, Caddebostan Maksim Gazino'sunun (MIGROS)yakınındaki büfe'de 'zümküfül' yenirdi (Bir çeşit sosisli sandoviç ) Yabancı filmlerin mekanı ise Budak Sineması'ydı (Şimdiki CKM). Yastıgını kapıp tahta iskemlelere yerleştirdikten sonra, çekirdeğini çıtlatarak izlenirdi filmler. Bazen bu sinemalarda Cem Karaca gibi o zamanın ünlü sesleri konserler verir, bazıları ağaç tepelerinden konser izlerdi.

Sonra sonra o köşkler birer birer yıkılmaya, yerlerin uzun uzun binalar dikilmeye, Cadde'deki evlerin yerlerini dükkanlar almaya, arabalar çoğalmaya, faytonlar yok olmaya, tekerlekli dondurmacıların yerini Algida'cılar almaya başladı. Ama ne mutlu ki tüm büyümeler, kalabalıklaşmalar rağmen 'Cadde'yi bozmayı başaramadı! O hala 'Cadde', İstanbul'un ,Türkiye'nin en güzide caddesi hala boydan boya yürümekten zevk aldığım, bir yerde oturup geleni geçeni izlemenin keyfini her yıl bir iki hafta yaşayabildiğim bir yer.

Galata' ya dogru...

Galata' ya dogru...

The best way to improve health care requires physicians and other stakeholders

My honest approach for how to improve the care is to support a methodology such as being self-serving. I would like to start a program to introduce a software-based point-of-care tool for obtaining patient feedback. This real time information can be used with clients to positively impact the patient experience, nurse engagement, physician (soft skills) competence and overall quality. In my perspective the criteria for fulfilling the demand for finding the best way to improve healthcare is that it need be simple to implement, impactful and cost effective. The most impact to healthcare improvement will come from process improvement and healthcare provider recruitment AND retention. The by-products will be reduced cost of care and improved patient satisfaction. This applies to hospitals and private practices. Based on current studies and the economy, supplying adequate healthcare to the community is already tough and is going to get more challenging. Recruiting sufficient healthcare coverage will boost revenue and provide some improvement to patient satisfaction (wait time and access). However, failure to retain the medical staff will significantly hurt the outcome. With high demand and low supply, it will be well worth the time and money to present "we have the greenest pastures here". The method mentioned above may be called such as point-of-care through successful implementations that may turn in to popular key parts of process improvement. You need to have some feedback from the patients and the physicians in order to measure the processes that should be or are currently being improved. In order to achieve this you have to create the acronym HOSPITAL to help those in Healthcare recall the numbers of different types of inefficiencies in any medical facility. Those who have been exposed to Six Sigma and Lean have an appreciation for improvement opportunities and generally view things through differently trained eyes that can see within all those facilities. Publishing the results of the similar programs online may offer a transparent access to the consumers to monitor these inefficiencies. Welcoming any feedback relative to this and encourage your staff to consider this method or similar training methods for their teams will be highly critical for the outcome. We have to understand that it is impossible to solve a problem that we are unaware of. By providing even the most basic tools at the lowest level possible, these problems have a way of surfacing. While everyone recognizes that healthcare systems and organizations need to improve, I think not enough time is spent on firstly identifying the key stakeholders, and secondly properly ENGAGING them. I strongly believe that not enough time is spent trying to engage physicians in this process. In my experience too many of these "improvement strategies" are top-down decisions by non-clinical managers who failed to conduct any research into what physicians might want or what stumbling blocks there are/were to get them to adopt the new technologies. EMR/EHR/CPOE are prime examples - all of these require a breakdown in the normal activity flow of providers, as it requires them to either find and log on to a terminal or carry a bulky instrument. Almost all clients and colleagues I have worked with resent and resist those methods. And look how few MDs are part of Healthcare consulting firm teams. IMHO, I believe more energy should be spent engaging rather than alienating MDs as a first step, then doing the same for patients in order to get buy in from the two key stakeholders as I see it. I've always found that engaging these stakeholders on projects from the beginning results in more buy-in and most importantly, better recommendations/outcomes (a better product).

ULTIMATE RESULTS

ULTIMATE RESULTS

Ilhan Arsel

Ilhan Arsel

BJK FOREVER

BJK FOREVER
Karga kartalların sırtına oturur ve boynunu ısırır. Kartal cevap vermez, kargayla savaşmaz; kargaya zaman veya enerji harcamaz, bunun yerine sadece kanatlarını açar ve göklerde yükselmeye başlar. Uçuş ne kadar yüksek olursa, karganın nefes alması o kadar zor olur ve sonunda karga oksijen eksikliği nedeniyle düşer. Kartaldan öğrenin ve kargalarla savaşmayın, sadece yükselmeye devam edin. Yolculuk için gelebilirler ama yakında düşecekler. Dikkat dağıtıcı şeylere yenik düşmenize izin vermeyin....yukarıdaki şeylere odaklanmaya devam edin ve yükselmeye devam edin!! Kartal ve Karga dersi